Microeconomics > Markets and Government > > Raising the Bar: The Intriguing Economics of Price Floors

Introduction: Price floors are the opposite of price ceilings; they set a minimum price for a good or service, higher than what the market would naturally dictate. Commonly seen in the agricultural sector, these controls ensure that farmers can earn a sustainable income by setting minimum prices for crops. Additionally, price floors are used in environmental policies, such as minimum prices on carbon emissions, to discourage pollution. Unlike price ceilings, price floors are set above the equilibrium price, leading to different market dynamics and outcomes.

Key Examples and Impacts:

  1. Agricultural Price Floors
    • + Minimum prices for fruits, vegetables, and other crops.
    • Market Effect: Producers are incentivized to increase supply, but consumer demand decreases at higher prices.
    • Result: Surpluses of agricultural products.
    • Government Intervention: Often, governments purchase the surplus. This surplus can be used in various ways, such as supplying school lunches or being destroyed.
  2. Carbon Emissions Price Floor
    • |+ Minimum prices for carbon emissions to curb pollution.
    • Market Effect: Encourages businesses to reduce pollution; cost of pollution becomes more tangible.
    • Result: A reduction in pollution levels, but potentially increased costs for businesses.
    • Policy Impact: Can lead to innovation in clean energy but may also impact economic competitiveness.
  3. Minimum Wage Laws
    • |+ A price floor on wages.
    • Market Effect: Encourages higher wages for workers, but businesses may hire less due to increased labor costs.
    • Result: Potential increase in worker income but risk of increased unemployment.
    • Policy Balance: Balancing worker welfare with employment opportunities is key.

More on #3:

The Ongoing Debate on Minimum Wage

The federal minimum wage debate is a perennial topic in U.S. economic policy, highlighting the balance between ensuring a livable income for workers and the potential impacts on employment and business costs. President Obama’s proposal in 2013 to increase the federal minimum wage, followed by the 2020 Democratic candidates’ push for a $15 hourly wage, reflects the ongoing discussion about income inequality and living standards.

When discussing this, it’s important to consider the concept of producer and consumer surplus. Raising the minimum wage might benefit workers earning lower wages (consumer surplus), but it could also increase labor costs for businesses (producer surplus). This debate often involves discussing the potential for job losses if businesses reduce their workforce in response to higher wage costs.

Moreover, the variation in minimum wage laws across states and cities adds another layer of complexity. Some places have higher local minimum wages than the federal standard, reflecting differences in living costs and economic conditions.

The work of Joshua Angrist, a Nobel laureate, provides valuable insights into this discussion. Angrist’s empirical research methods have significantly contributed to understanding the real-world impacts of policies like the minimum wage. His work often involves natural experiments that offer robust evidence on the effects of such policies on employment and income.

Minimum Wage in America: A Timeline
https://www.history.com/news/minimum-wage-america-timeline

What You Need To Know About The Minimum Wage Debate
https://www.forbes.com/advisor/personal-finance/minimum-wage-debate/

Conclusion: Price floors, like price ceilings, are a form of economic intervention used to address perceived societal problems. They often come with trade-offs: while they can provide stability or promote certain ethical standards (like fair wages or environmental protection), they can also lead to market inefficiencies like surpluses or unemployment. Understanding these trade-offs is crucial in evaluating the effectiveness and desirability of price floors as a policy tool.